Global Trade and Global Finance
By Mathew Watson
Introduction
The globalization of
trade and finance
The regulation of
global trade
The regulation of
global finance
Conclusion
Reader's Guide
This chapter will introduce students to
important issues in the conduct of global trade and global finance. It shows
that the two spheres are regulated by different governance institutions, but
that disturbances in one sphere can result in related disturbances in the
other. This corresponds to one of the most widely cited definitions of economic
globalization, where globalization is understood as the increased sensitivity
of one part of the world economy to events originating elsewhere. A brief
outline is provided of the increased turnover of trade and finance flows in
recent decades. However, it is not immediately obvious that such flows are genuinely
global in their geographical scope, because they appear to be heavily
concentrated in those countries which have shaped the international balance of
power to their own advantage. The remaining sections focus on the institutional
history of the regulation of trade and financial flows. Once again, they
suggest the significance of the international balance of power, demonstrating
that a global elite has successfully imprinted its interests in prevailing
institutionalized regulatory norms. The political dominance of this elite has
generally overridden the search for systemic regulatory coherence, enhancing
the degree to which difficulties in either trade or finance create knock-on
problems in the other sphere.
What is global trade?
Global trade, also known as international trade, is simply the import and export of goods and
services across international boundaries. Goods and services that enter into a
country for sale are called imports.
What
is global financial?
The global financial system is the worldwide framework of
legal agreements, institutions, and both formal and informal economic actors
that together facilitate international flows of financial capital for purposes of investment and trade
financing.
Introduction
The 1970s was a troubled, even crisis,
decade for the advanced industrialized countries of the Western world. Growth
rates fell quite substantially from their post- Second World War plateau, with
both unemployment and inflation increasing rapidly. This led to the
identification of a qualitatively new economic phenomenon, stagflation, in
which advanced industrialized countries seemed to be powerless to re-energize
their economies but paid the price for attempting to do so in the form of
accelerating prices. The political response to perceptions of such
powerlessness was a concerted reaction against government intervention in the
economy. National controls on the free movement of capital, money, goods,
services, and people were progressively eased, and the language of ‘markets’
began to dominate the way politicians talked about their economic priorities.
International institutions were also given extra authority to deprive markets
of the overwhelmingly national character that they had displayed in the 1970s
and to superimpose an increasingly global character in its place (see Ch. 11).
The 2010s look set to be at least a
similarly troubled decade, with all current predictions for the trajectory of
the world economy in the immediate aftermath of the Great Recession suggesting
that the end of the turbulence is by no means in sight. Growth rates amongst
the advanced industrialized countries have been more badly affected since the
onset of the global financial crisis than at any time in the 1970s, while
unemployment is considerably higher now than it was then. As yet, though, there
has been no evidence of the systematic rethink of governance priorities which
occurred last time the world economy was gripped by a sense of endemic crisis.
There have certainly been changes in individual aspects of
regulation—especially in relation to the banking practices which are widely
held to have precipitated the crisis—but the broader framework of regulation
has remained intact. In general, both Western governments and the global
governance institutions have stuck to the old story that, in essence, markets
know best.
The biggest surprise of the post-2007
global financial crisis is just how little looks likely to change as a result of
the public policy response. The language of markets and the image of a largely
self-regulating world economy still tend to dominate when political parties
say that they cannot protect jobs throughout the economy because of the
overriding priority of paying back recent record increases in public debt.
Ironically, though, the debt was only initially run up to such an extent to protect
the financial bottom line of an otherwise bankrupt banking sector as well as
the jobs in that sector. Governments have had to bail out the banks while
refusing to support other industries, so the argument goes, otherwise global
markets themselves will enact their own form of retribution by making the
underlying economic situation even worse. It is global markets, then, that are
commonly seen to have dictated the printing of money in enormous sums to be
pumped freely into the banking system, and it is also global markets that
allegedly dictate the embrace of austerity and its accompanying harsh economic
medicines for the rest of the population.
This might sound a bit like a
Frankenstein’s Monster scenario, in which the creation—here, economic globalization—runs
out of control and turns on its creator. In Shelleys original story, though,
the Monster ended its vengeful attacks on those who Frankenstein held dear by
taking its own life, but we are currently a long way from the same ending with
respect to economic globalization. This is because it is not globalization per
se which somehow determines what governments can and cannot do in the wake of
the global financial crisis. Rather, it is the structure of interests embedded
within the choice of how to regulate economic globalization today which serves
to circumscribe the range of possible outcomes. These interests show no signs of
voluntarily withdrawing from the scene in the same way that Frankenstein’s
Monster did, which is why a replica of Shelleys denouement is not to be
expected. The chapter proceeds to investigate this structure of interests, but
first a few words are in order about the prevailing pattern of global trade and
global finance itself.
The
globalization of trade and finance
There remains significant disagreement in
the academic genuine economic globalization actually is (Hay 2011) literature
about just how prevalent the trend towards The word ‘globalization’ has become
synonymous with the time period of enhanced national market integration since
the crisis of the 1970s, but it also tends to be used—with varying degrees of
analytical precision—to describe the pattern of interdependent economic flows
which has resulted (see Ch. 1). There have certainly been large increases over
the last forty years in the integration of national markets for both traded
goods and financial flows, but this does not mean in itself that the ensuing
market arrangements incorporate all countries of the world in any way evenly.
As Held et al. (1999) have argued, it is important to differentiate between
the ‘intensity’ and the ‘extensity’ of supposedly global flows of trade and
finance. Intensity measures reveal the degree to which national economic
borders are now traversed by such flows: they indicate whether there are more
than previously but remain silent on their geographical character. Extensity
measures, by contrast, focus on the geographical dispersal of contemporary
trade and finance, asking not simply whether there are more such flows but also
whether they systematically incorporate more countries of the world. The
distinction, then, is between the speeding up and the spreading out of flows of
trade and finance. Somewhat confusingly, the single word ‘globalization’ is
frequently used to describe both resulting patterns, even though it would
clearly be preferable to keep them analytically distinct.
What seems to have occurred in general is
the emergence of particular globalization ‘hotspots’ centred on the most
advanced industrialized countries, in which there has been a significant
intensification of cross- border economic activity (Pickel 2005). Intensity measures
therefore appear to capture the essence of these changes better, although this
should not detract from the fact that in some very important cases—the emergence
of the BRICs economies, for instance, as well as the continued rise of East
Asia—a greater extensity of economic globalization is also apparent (see Ch.
5). At the same time, though, many of the poorest countries of the world remain
largely untouched by the new economic structures and appear to have little
connection to the prevailing structure of globalization hotspots. They have
been largely bypassed, both intensively and extensively.
Partly this is an issue of development,
because the organization of cross-border economic activities has tended to
focus only on the most advanced sectors of the world economy. Partly it is an
issue of political asymmetries in the regulatory system for global trade and
global finance, with the advanced industrialized
countries keeping most of the economic
gains from globalization for themselves. As development issues are dealt with
elsewhere in the book (see Ch. 20), this chapter focuses instead primarily on
the regulatory principles on which global trade and global finance are today
grounded. The aim is to highlight the means through which the balance of power
in the inter-state system is imprinted on the regulation of global trade and
global finance. This will enable students to conceptualize the tendency
towards economic globalization as a clearly political process. Insofar as the
crisis of the 1970s resulted in greater trust being placed in market mechanisms
to guide economic activity, for those markets to exist as concrete historical
phenomena they first had to be ‘made’ politically (see Box 21.1).
When treated as a purely economic
phenomenon, the most frequently cited indicator of globalization is the
eye-catching increase in world trade witnessed in the last forty years. Here,
then, we see evidence of the successful constitution of ever deeper
international markets for traded goods. The relevant increase is demonstrated
best by looking at standardized figures for the volume of world exports,
because this allows for meaningful direct comparisons to be made. Taking the
2000 figure as the baseline number of 100—which itself corresponded in value
terms to approximately US$8.6 trillion of world trade—this compares with
standardized numbers of 22 for 1970, 37 for 1980, and 54 for 1990. In other
words, in this take-off and early maturation stage of economic globalization,
the volume of world exports grew by roughly a factor of 4.5 between 1970 and
2000, a factor of 3 between 1980 and 2000, and a factor of 2 between 1990 and
2000 alone. This signifies an accelerating trend, and further increases in global
trade after 2000 continued to be marked until the destabilizing impact of the
subprime crisis of 2007-8 (World Trade Organization. The figures for 2009, in fact, represent the largest
post-Second World War year-on-year reduction in world trade: by recent historical
standards the drop was a barely believable 12 per cent. There was a significant
rebound of 13.8 per cent in 2010, followed by slower growth of 5 per cent in
2011 and slower still projected growth of 3.7 per cent for 2012, but all this
means that world trade is still significantly trending upwards despite the
collapse in 2009. Between 1991 and 2011 the trend increase in merchandise
exports was an annual 5.5 per cent, and the dollar value of world trade reached
US$18.2 trillion in 2011, moving beyond the previous peak of US$16.0 trillion
in 2008 (World Trade Organization 2012).
The figures also show that the world
economy was becoming more systematically open to global trade from 1970s
onwards. The relevant indicator here is the ratio of growth in global trade to
growth in global GDP. If the two numbers are exactly the same, and therefore
the ratio is 1:1, all increases in world export demand are fully accounted for
by the fact that the world economy is becoming richer as a whole, and not by
the fact that it is becoming generically more open to trade. However, taking
1970-2000 as a single time period, the ratio was 1.77:1, showing that increases
in global trade were almost double those of global GDP. Between 2000 and 2011,
even allowing for the collapse of merchandise trade in 2009, it has been more
than double (all figures calculated from World Trade Organization 2007, 2012).
On their own, though, the figures here can
only demonstrate unequivocally an increasing intensity of global trade flows.
The extensity figures are significantly more complex and can, in truth, only
be presented on a case-by-case basis to conclude with any certainty that a
particular country is experiencing the globalization of trade extensively as
well as intensively. In general, extensity factors are more likely to be
apparent the more deeply embedded a country is within a regional trading
agreement (Farrell, Hettne, and Van Langenhove 2005). Yet even here the geographical
pattern of the observed extensity will almost certainly be more pronounced
within the regional bloc than beyond its borders. Those borders in fact often
present a good proxy for the outer limits of the globalization of trade flows.
The same tends to be true of financial
flows which are activated as a means of ensuring that new plant and machinery
can be paid for in one country but physically established in another. This is
called foreign direct investment and is the most obvious example of the
extensity of flows of global finance (Jensen 2008).
However, most of the more remarkable
changes ii global financial markets since the 1970s are of a qualitatively
different nature (see Box 21.2). They do no: require money to change hands in
any conventional sense, and therefore the relevant flows do not have a
geographical character consistent with a movement across space. Most financial
markets today have a global component, insofar as advances in computer
technology allow their trading relationships to be accessed by anyone who has a
suitable network connection. Yet the trading itself typically takes place
through highly capitalized and reputable counterparties—banks, insurance
companies, hedge funds, professional investment bodies, pension funds, etc.—
swapping giant IOUs, which are either added to or subtracted from their
‘paper’ position at the end of each day’s trading. At most in this instance it
might be possible to talk about intensity measures.
However, we should be under no illusions
about just how significant trading flows on financial market: now are. The
average daily turnover on world currency markets alone was US$3.98 trillion in
2010, up by one fifth from the previous survey in 2007. This means that while
world merchandise trade has increased on average by 5.5 per cent per year between
1991 and 2011 over the same time period average daily turnover on world
currency markets has increased in total by a staggering 675 per cent (Bank for
International Settlement 2010). To write the most up-to-date figure out in
long-hand requires the addition of ten noughts after the ‘3’, the ‘9’, and the
‘8’. Flows of global finance consequent completely dwarf flows of global trade,
with the doll value of currency market turnover alone being pretty much eighty
times higher than the dollar value of countries’ export activities in
aggregate. Moreover outstanding positions on currency markets are themselves
only a fraction of those on derivatives contracts, the type of financial
instrument to which banks found themselves hopelessly overexposed after the sub-prime
crisis. While not as big in purely monetary terms, bond markets have also
recently been in the news as the sub-prime crisis evolved through various other
forms into the eurozone debt crisis (see Box 21.6). It was adverse patterns of
trading on bond markets which pushed the debt repayment schedules of Italy,
Spain, Portugal, Cyprus, Ireland, and, in particular, Greece so high that they
were required to seek external support in exchange for commitments to enhanced
levels of public spending cuts.
Trading patterns on financial markets tend
to become newsworthy in circumstances of high speculative pressure. A large
proportion of the US$3.98 trillion of daily turnover on world currency markets,
for instance, now represents currencies being bought and sold for purely
speculative purposes (Kenen 1996). Such speculation represents two things. On
the one hand, it is a bet placed on the power of private financial institutions
to force the movement in relative currency prices that they most desire. On the
other hand, it is a bet placed against governments’ ability to maintain a
truly autonomous policy course in the face of the disciplinary power of private
financial institutions.
However, the source of such attacks is by
no means evenly spread geographically, because neither is the ownership of
financial assets. Global finance is spatially
concentrated in the North Atlantic
economy. Indeed, the concentration is so marked—and intensifying— that the
adjective ‘global’ is questionable as a description of both the character of
financial flows in the world economy and the recent crisis which ensued when
those flows suddenly dried up. According to figures produced by the McKinsey
Global Institute just before the onset of the crisis in 2007, two-thirds of the
world’s US$196 trillion of active financial assets were held in the US, the UK,
and Western Europe. Despite the continued rise of East Asia in global trade and
the emergence of China as a genuine trading superpower, global financial flows
have not followed the same pattern in a gradual shift in their centre of
gravity to the East (Hirst, Thompson, and Bromley 2009).
Key Points
There are more flows of trade and finance
around the world economy today than at any previous time, but care should be
taken about the precise sense in which such flows are labelled as 'global'.
The increase in world trade since 1970 is
dramatic, although it might be that the process of regional economic
integration accounts for those changes more readily than the process of genuine
global economic integration. Trading on financial markets only very rarely
involves money physically changing hands, so that the consequences of such trading
are much more likely to have a genuinely global reach than its pattern.
The
regulation of global trade
The Bretton Woods Conference was held in
1944 in the New England town of that name. The Conference was attended by
forty-four soon to be victorious Allied countries from 1-22 July of that year.
It was organized in an attempt to design a post-war governance structure for
the Western world that would prevent the world economy from returning to the
Great Depression that had so blighted lives and livelihoods in the preceding
decade (see Ch. 11). The new Keynesian economic theory of that time suggested
that it was output rather than prices which adjusted to global imbalances in
trade, thus forcing national economies into a repetitive cycle of reduced
production and job losses. The ensuing severe rises in unemployment preceded
the political mobilization of many European populations to radical right-wing
ideologies in the 1930s, and Keynes was determined that the structure of global
trade should be stabilized in order to prevent history from repeating itself on
this point.
His priority was to create a multilateral
institution that would facilitate continual expansions in global trade. The
proposed institution was to be called the International Trade Organization
(ITO). However, concerted dissent domestically within US politics meant that
President Truman did not even bother sending the final bill to Congress for
ratification. It was deemed too interventionist for US politicians’ tastes, for
it would have introduced common conditions on things such as labour and
environmental standards in order to create a genuine level playing field for
the conduct of global..
Box 21.1
What is international trade?
At its most basic, international trade
occurs when the citizens of one country produce a good that is subsequently
consumed by the citizens of another country. There is consequently a
geographical mismatch between the site of production and the site of
consumption, with the good travelling across at least one national border to
connect the producer economically with the consumer. The country producing the
good for sale elsewhere in the world is the exporter; the country in which the
good is eventually sold is the importer.
Box 21.2 What is international finance?
Even though the language and economic
imagery used to describe the two is often the same, in practice the dynamics of
international finance differ substantially from those of international trade.
Except for the case of foreign direct investment, it i is very difficult to
think of examples from the financial sphere in which one country ‘produces'
money for another country to 'consume'. Activity generally takes place on
financial markets through taking paper positions using advanced information
technology networks—financial products only very rarely flow across borders in
any straightforward import/export sense. What makes finance international is
the scale of its reach into, and influence over, global politics.
I have to voice my passion for your kindness giving support to those people that should have guidance on this important matter.company formation services in dubai
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteThis comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDelete
ReplyDeleteHi,
Thanks for Nice and Informative Post. This post is really contains lot more information about This Topic. I will share this information with my friend Joel Sharpe, he is a finance student.
This Post explores importance of global trade and global finance. I appreciate your research level for this post, I will share this information with my friend Ethan Nordean, he is in finance field i'm sure like this great post. Thank you for this informative post.
ReplyDeleteWow, What a Excellent post. I really found this to much informatics. It is what i was searching for.I would like to suggest you that please keep sharing such type of info.Thanks investment adviser compliance
ReplyDeleteHow to retire early in the UK I am impressed. I don't think Ive met anyone who knows as much about this subject as you do. You are truly well informed and very intelligent. You wrote something that people could understand and made the subject intriguing for everyone. Really, great blog you have got here.
ReplyDeleteThanks for a very interesting blog. What else may I get that kind of info written in such a perfect approach? I’ve a undertaking that I am simply now operating on, and I have been at the look out for such info. Gifts for investors
ReplyDeleteThe top most betting prediction sites all over the world Betting prediction site
ReplyDeleteWonderful post
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing
Digital Yuan
Its informative and intresting post thanks for sharing DLF share price
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing this valuable post. Being an International Trade finance service provider, we always look for the recent update about Global trade Market.
ReplyDeleteLets connect on google news!
Thanks for sharing the best information and suggestions, I love your content, and they are very nice and very useful to us. If you are looking for the best world financial news, then visit I-investonline.com. I appreciate the work you have put into this.
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing! Good content, no doubt!
ReplyDeleteOne suggestion from my side: Design can be improved for better understanding of readers like we have posted the same guide on our platform "Emerio Banque":
Visit: https://www.emeriobanque.com/blogs/what-is-international-trade-finance-how-does-it-work-and-types
Thanks for sharing the best information and suggestions, I love your content, and they are very nice and very useful to us. If you are looking for the best Iinvest, then visit i-invest Online. I appreciate the work you have put into this.
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing this amazing informative post with us i found this helpful for motivational and inspirational consultancy services. Learn more about Shezad Nawab MBE's inspiring journey and services. Global Trade
ReplyDelete